Microsoft word - forhan final edits as of dec 1st.doc
This is MINE. No, this is OURS: Holding “Big Pharma” To Account Karen Forhan M.A. Communications and Culture, Ryerson University & York University Research Associate, Robarts Centre for Canadian Studies York University www.robarts.yorku.ca December 1, 2008 Table of Contents
“Once Upon A Time There Was A Market …". 9
Putting A Price-Tag On Ideas: Intellectual Property Rights. 11
Look Who’s Talking: A Struggle Of Publics In A Global Marketplace . 13
Big Rules, Big Money, “Big Pharma” Ideology. 15
Where Is The “Progress” Here? Where Is The “Development”? . 20
Setting Global Rules: The ‘Nitty-Gritty’ Of The WTO TRIPS Agreement. 23
TRIPS As “Organized Irresponsibility” . 26
South Africa: The Protests Of Aids Activists’ Are Heard. 28
Brazil’s Crusade Against “Big Pharma”. 33
The Battle At Seattle: An “Icon Of Dissent” . 35
A Reframed Agenda: The Doha Declaration. 37
‘TRIPS-Plus’ Conditions And U.S. Free Trade Agreements . 44
I. Public And Private Partnerships. 47
II. Generic Drugs: A Global Powerhouse . 49
III. "Big Pharma" And Global Activism . 50
Appendix II: Glossary of Relevant TRIPS Terms . 54
Executive Summary
This report examines the World Trade Organization’s (WTO) Trade-Related Aspects of
Intellectual Property Rights (TRIPS) Agreement and pharmaceuticals, “Big Pharma’s”
role in defining the initial agenda, and the social and political activism that emerged to
fight for access to medicines. Using Nancy Fraser’s multifaceted public sphere
perspective as a theoretical lens, the report analyzes the roles of relevant actors through
her differentiations of “strong” publics, “weak” publics, and “subaltern counterpublics.”
Central Findings It’s all about balance: intellectual property rights and the ‘Common(s)~ The ethical
questions that the issue of TRIPS and pharmaceuticals raise are part of a much broader
phenomenon of public concern—the commodification or expropriation of the
‘Commons.’ In recent years, there has been a steady influx of privatization, which has
allowed private/corporate interests to take hold of things that were not previously
classified as commodities. A “commodity fiction” was formulated so that water resources
could be privatized, so that the genetic code could be owned, and so that information
regarding essential medicines could be restricted solely for Big Pharma’s commercial
purposes. As a staple of market economies, the private property rights system is held in
high regard for good reason; however, as the TRIPS issue clearly illuminates, there must
be an appropriate balance between the sanctity of private property and the health of the
Common(s). It is imperative to keep these more fundamental concerns in mind when
addressing these issues because it helps one see beyond the “red tape” of these laws and
helps one deconstruct who is manufacturing them for their own benefit.
Underlying significance of the WTO’s initial implementation of TRIPS ~ The inclusion of
pharmaceuticals in the TRIPS Agreement successfully legislated an agenda with Big
Pharma ideology at its core – namely big rules and big money. The result of its
implementation was a constructed ‘ideal’ market for both the corporate interests of Big
Pharma as well as those of the developed nations in which these corporations operate
(“stronger publics”). Therefore, with little consideration of larger global public health
concerns, the agenda that TRIPS set completely neglected the poor in developing nations
who are unable to access essential medicines. These “weaker publics” were given no
voice let alone a thought in the WTO’s agenda. “Big Pharma” as a star player ~ TheBig Pharma industry has been granted such a
‘larger than life’ position of power that the corporations which have been frantically
mapping out the human genome, have actually been allowed to patent what they
discover. In other words, Big Pharma has been given the right to own the genetic codes of
life. Patents are a lucrative business and therefore, when TRIPS was written, Big Pharma
lobbied for a standardized international regime that would protect its patents irrespective
of the country. Naturally, when governments of developing nations (like South Africa
and Brazil) began challenging the monopoly on the utilization of these patents, Big
Pharma, along with the developed nations in which these corporations are based, brought
costly lawsuits against the challengers. Thus, not only did Big Pharma play a major role
in writing the agenda, it also acted as an enforcer of it as well.“Subaltern Counterpublics”: A force to be reckoned with ~ In addition to the
governments of a few developing nations that took a stand against Big Pharma and the
TRIPS regime, there were also numerous NGOs (like Oxfam, Médecins sans Frontières
(MSF), and the Treatment Action Campaign (TAC) and social movements (such as the
‘Battle at Seattle’) which took up the fight for access to medicines. These entities
represent “subaltern counterpublics.” Their actions came together to construct a counter-
discourse that eventually influenced the WTO to reframe its agenda and adopt the Doha
Declaration on TRIPS and Public Health. The successes of the political and social
activism taken within these subaltern counterpublics reveal an exciting change in the
geopolitical landscape of power. The global public sphere is recognizing an increasingly
diverse number of publics whose opinions and needs were previously unacknowledged in
the dominant discourse. This transformation is empowering people who traditionally did
not have a voice in matters of global governance. As these relations are changing before
our eyes, we must try to reconceptualize how we perceive global power relations. We
must challenge ourselves to adapt our conceptual tools for the contemporary landscape,
and that is why Nancy Fraser’s multifaceted public sphere perspective has been
invaluable to the deliberations in this report.
Key Concepts The ‘Common(s)’: spaces, resources, and goods that are not expropriated by the private
property rights system, meaning that they are not owned by any particular private body.
In addition to the Common(s) signifying traditional goods like water for example, it can
also signify more abstract things such as the communicative practices and collaboration
between individuals. This is further elaborated upon in Michael Hardt and Antonio
Neoliberal: an ideology that promotes profit-driven, bottom-line thinking and free market
economic principles (privatization, deregulation, liberalization of trade, etc.).
“Big Pharma”: this is now a popularized term which represents the multinational and
multimillion dollar pharmaceutical industry and the corporations that are a part of it.
Public sphere: “a body of ‘private persons’ assembled to discuss matters of public
concern or ‘common interest’” (Fraser, 112). “It is the space in which citizens deliberate
about their common affairs, and hence an institutionalized arena of discursive
Globalization: characterized by national economies becoming increasingly integrated,
ever-increasing flows of communications and financial activity around the globe, and a
growing presence of multinational and transnational corporations, organizations, and
social movements. Different actors with conflicting agendas utilize these conditions
creating fascinating power relations as illustrated throughout the contents of this report.
The most prominent tension discussed here exists between those who promote a
neoliberal vision of economic globalization versus those of the “anti-globalization”
movement who are opposed to the neoliberal agenda.
“This is MINE”
As you settle in to read this paper, you bring with you an often-overlooked assumption.
You naturally assume that the author – that is, me, owns every paragraph and page. It is
just understood that in being my mind’s creation, this paper is my private property and
therefore, it is my right to restrict its use as I see fit. There is an assumption that it is the
reader’s duty to respect that. However, what if this paper held information that would
save a life? Would the rules still be the same? What if this paper held information that
could save one million lives? Would my right to its restriction still be respected? What if
there was an international regime that prevented the effective sharing of information that
When the World Trade Organization (WTO) decided to include pharmaceutical
drugs and processes in its Trade-Related Aspects of Intellectual Property Rights (TRIPS)
Agreement, it made an unsettling choice. The TRIPS regime called on WTO Member-
states to regulate pharmaceutical patents according to a homogenized neoliberal
framework; one that was constructed to privilege the interests of multinational
pharmaceutical corporations (Big Pharma) as well as those of the developed nations in
which they operate. This follows a familiar trend in how economic globalization has
facilitated a concentration of political and economic power into ever-larger international
social institutions. Nation-states are more malleable to the policies and norms set by
international institutions, and multinational corporations have become a prominent
beacon of influence whose control spreads not only geographically to all corners of the
globe, but also to all corners of what can be considered the ‘global Commons’ by
In an increasingly global information economy, the corporate hand extends its
reach further with the intellectual property rights system. In relation to TRIPS and access
to medicines, the dissemination of information can be, quite literally, a matter of life and
death, thus raising fundamental philosophical questions about balancing private property
rights and the health of the Common. Fortunately, there is a strong subaltern power that is
creating a counter-discourse that does just that – cuts through the red tape of a legislated
“industrial fatalism”1 to tackle the more fundamental questions and fight for an agenda
that takes into account more than profits as the bottom line. Nongovernmental
organizations (NGOs), the governments of developing nations, and transnational social
movements are accumulating power through a backlash against a market-driven,
neoliberal economic globalization. In these subaltern counterpublics, people escape from
their ‘communities of fate’ (no matter what their geographical location, no matter what
their class or ethnicity) to mobilize together into ‘communities of choice,’ which strive
for a common goal and achieve social change.
When analyzing the issue of global intellectual property rights and access to
essential medicines for the world’s poor, one sees how something as supra-structural as
the WTO’s international agenda can be reset by concerned citizens working in unison.
This report will examine how the efforts of subaltern counterpublics have pressured Big
Pharma in order to hijack power away from the industry and the WTO by demanding
more accountability and protection for global health concerns.
1 The concept of “industrial fatalism” is a term used by Ulrich Beck to describe a prevailing mentality that rationalizes everything to the extreme so that things seem more functional, calculated and reasoned. This can lead to the rationalization of larger risks and hazards that have no accountability to human interests. “Industrial fatalism” is linked with the standard critiques of ideological notions of “progress.”
“Once upon a time there was a market …”
As much as some place the ‘self-regulating’ market on a pedestal, it is people who have
created that story,and people who revere that neoliberal image. Market economies are
cultural constructs just like the laws manufactured to govern them. One of the main
themes that Karl Polanyi emphasizes in, The Great Transformation is that “man’s
economy, as a rule, is submerged in his social relationships” (Polanyi 48). Despite
attitudes to the contrary, items that are bought and sold on the market do not have an
inherent quality that rationalizes their becoming commodities. The necessary justification
for any commodification is what Polanyi calls a “commodity fiction.”
Polanyi argued that the rendering of things not originally produced for sale
as commodities required their reconceptualization, and thus their
fictionalization, as “property” … A story needed to be told about these
resources which was not necessarily linked to their existence or social
production but rather narrated as a propensity to be organized through
This “fictionalization” continues to dictate the commodification of more and more
elements of our lives further entrenching our social relations within the rules of the
market – providing further specifications on what is considered ‘property’ and what is
not. The deep-rooted conception of private property rights and their justification can be
traced back to the theories of liberal philosopher, John Locke and the post-Kantian
idealist, Georg Wilhelm Friedrich Hegel.
For Hegel, property rights represented the creation and protection of individuality;
they “protect the individual from the state and competing individuals in society by
carving out a sovereign space” (May 126). Locke’s thoughts on private property are
especially significant since he initiated a long line of liberal thinkers who have
continuously adopted his theories. Locke said, “He by his labour does, as it were, enclose
it from the Common … where there is enough and as good left in the Common for
others” (Andreasson 5). Interestingly, somewhere along the way, liberal thinkers ‘forgot’
Locke’s assertion about balancing private property rights with the need to ensure that
there is enough left in the Common for others. Again, this omission was not ‘natural’; it
was chosen and the choice was rationalized by pragmatic or economic arguments, which
are now inseparable from ideas of private property.
One of these central economic arguments is that a scarcity of any resource drives
innovation. When goods are scarce, the costs of attaining them are high so that,
theoretically, people are inspired to innovate in order to avoid the costs. The other main
rationalizing argument is that “efficient resource use is established through the use of
markets in which property is exchanged and transferred to those who can make the best
use of it” (May 127). Therefore, property rights are supposed to regulate an “efficient”
use of limited resources and simultaneously guard against what Garret Hardin describes
in his article as “The Tragedy of the Commons.” Hardin claimed that if the Commons
were not regulated, individuals would use its resources for their own self-interest to the
point of depletion. The basic idea behind this tragedy scenario is that: “Freedom in the
Commons brings ruin to all” (May 128).
From this perspective, enclosing the Commons through a private property rights
system is justified for the social good because, as Hardin declares, “while it replaces
merit or justice with wealth as the key allocation mechanism, ‘injustice is preferable to
total ruin’” (May 129). Thus, to avoid so-called ‘ruin,’ those who produce the laws for
private property rights relentlessly drew and continue to redraw the legal boundaries for
what is considered yours, mine, and the “Commons,” which is ours.
Putting a Price-Tag on Ideas: Intellectual Property Rights
The commodification of information and ideas presents interesting nuances regarding the
issue of private property rights since there is a unique relationship between information
The production of ideas, images, and knowledges is not only conducted in
[the] common –no one really thinks alone, all thought is produced in
collaboration with the past and present thought of others – but also each
new idea and image invites and opens new collaborations (Hardt and
The collaboration involved in the production and dissemination of information and
knowledge not only functions through the Common, but it also creates more ideas for the
Common which others, in turn, can use as a resource to produce yet even more ideas.
Intellectual property rights (IPRs) are “legal and institutional devices to protect creations
of the mind such as inventions, works of art and literature, and designs” (Dutfield 533).
They are the legal means through which ideas are commodified and their use restricted.
Scholars such as Manuel Castells assert that currently the dominant ‘mode of
development’ is “informationalism” in which “the source of productivity lies in the
technology of knowledge generation, information processing, and symbol
communication” (Castells 17). Complementary to this, Hardt and Negri identify the
“historical tendency” of our time as a “hegemony of immaterial production,” which
means that “immaterial labour” (labour related to information processing, generation, and
dissemination) essentially frames all other existing labour relations (Hardt and Negri
141). Since information is the most valuable economic resource in “informationalism”
and “immaterial production,” it is not surprising that the most sophisticated forms of
property rights in existence are now intellectual property rights.
The origination of intellectual property right laws in the West is rooted in the
‘privileges’ granted to inventors in fifteenth century Venice and sixteenth century
England along with other places in Europe. These privileges, granted as part of a
package, required the inventors to commit to teaching apprentices and to publicizing their
new method and/or technology. Thus, along with the attached economic benefits of the
granted privilege, the inventors had a duty to make their innovations accessible to as
many people as possible (May 132). “The subsequent history of intellectual property has
reversed this logic to make intellectual property itself the right which benefits society.
This has been a political reversal, not some ‘natural’ development, or refinement of law”
When it comes to knowledge and information, these arguments regarding scarcity
as a driver of innovation do not seem to hold true. This thereby presents a problem for
justifying the commodification of the social good. As Christopher May so eloquently puts
it: “If the social good served by knowledge and information is related to availability …
then the enforced scarcity of intellectual property becomes problematic” (May 130).
When people can use the same knowledge without damaging the benefits that can be
taken from that knowledge simultaneously, how does one justify the use of patents and
copyrights to construct a false scarcity of information, which imposes harmful costs to so
many people because that information is being restricted? What if this dilemma leads to a
tragedy of the “anti-commons”? Here the under-utilization of resources leads to
Whether we choose to pay attention or not, the private property rights system
progressively encloses more and more of what is referred to as the ‘global Commons’ –
including lifesaving knowledge and information. As the institution of private property
extends its reach to new geographical territories and commodifies important aspects of
our lives, one should question, who is setting the agenda for the development of these
laws and who is benefiting from that agenda?
Look Who’s Talking: A Struggle of Publics in a Global Marketplace
Jürgen Habermas’ “public sphere” is paraphrased by Nancy Fraser as being: “a body of
‘private persons’ assembled to discuss matters of public concern or ‘common interest’”
(Fraser 112). Habermas’ view of the public sphere is characterized as being an
overarching public sphere made up of one large body, to which, theoretically, all
‘citizens’ should have access. Yet, Fraser argues that multiple publics exist: “strong
publics,” “weak publics,” and “subaltern counterpublics.” What differentiates these
publics, she theorizes, is their location within power relations of dominance and
subordination and by how much decision-making influence each public holds
Although it is sometimes argued that global capitalismoperates through a
‘seamless’ mechanism of adjustment and price-setting, the rules of this mechanism have
been constructed by international organizations like the WTO. Therefore, groups that
have the power to influence the agenda of the WTO construct international policies that
have an impact on the global community in a profound way.
When considering the issue of global intellectual property rights and access to
medicines, the weaker public would be the disadvantaged people of developing countries,
who are deprived of essential medicines and whose voices are ignored in the negotiations
for their rights to these medicines – the group Paul Collier coins “the bottom billion.” The
stronger public is composed of multinational pharmaceutical corporations (Big Pharma)
and developed countries, which traditionally have more influence in the decision-making
of the dominant discourse; that is, in ‘writing the rules of the game’ – the WTO’s
legislation. NGOs, and the governments of some developing countries involved in this
battle, embody Fraser’s subaltern counterpublics since they are “parallel discursive
arenas where members of subordinated social groups invent and circulate
counterdiscourses to formulate oppositional interpretations of their identities, interests,
and needs” (Fraser 123). They have less enforceable decision-making powers than
multinational corporations or the governments of developed countries, but their
impressive strength stems from their ability to establish a counter-discourse against the
WTO conferences and the official legislation documents that result from these
conferences set the international legal parameters for the patentability of medicines for all
WTO Member-states. Picture the WTO legislative process as a conversation. The
stronger publics attempt to frame the WTO’s legislative discourse in terms of protecting
private intellectual property rights. The subaltern counterpublics attempt to reframe the
issue so that the protection of global public health is not governed by market principles as
the overarching guideline; these groups hold the humanitarian interests of the world’s
poor as the primary focus. The stronger public sets the agenda to create laws that
construct a neoliberal marketplace, and the agenda is subsequently reset by subaltern
We can trace the first significant move in the WTO’s legislative conversation
regarding international intellectual property rights and access to medicines back to the
WTO’s Uruguay Round in 1994. This was where the Trade-Related Aspects of
Intellectual Property Rights (TRIPS) Agreement was discussed and subsequently,
implemented. This Agreement sets out the minimum standards of patent protection that
all WTO members must meet, creating an international regime governing copyrights,
patents, trademarks, and any other issues relating to intellectual property. The
patentability of pharmaceutical processes and products was included in the Agreement as
well. Through the creation of TRIPS and its inclusion of pharmaceuticals, the stronger
publics of the WTO extended a neoliberal arm out into the global Commons to grab hold
of invaluable information. To understand the impact of NGOs in establishing a counter-
discourse to Big Pharma, it is first necessary to recognize how the interests of Big
Pharma were written into the ‘dominant’ discourse of the WTO’s original global
Big Rules, Big Money, Big Pharma Ideology
Pfizer Chairman Emeritus, Edmund Taylor Pratt Jr.’s speech in 1995 to the U.S.
The [Intellectual Property Committee, which Pfizer helped found] helped
to convince U.S. officials that we should take a tough stance on
intellectual property issues, and that led to trade-related intellectual
property rights being included on the GATT agenda when negotiations
began in Punta del Este, Uruguay, in 1986. . The current GATT victory,
which established provisions for intellectual property protection, resulted
from the hard-fought efforts of the U.S. government and U.S. businesses,
including Pfizer, over the past three decades. We’ve been in it from the
beginning, taking a leadership role (Wallach and Woodall 94-95).
Multinational corporations (MNCs) are fond of “global rules” that they can take
advantage of in any country in which they choose to operate. Therefore, MNCs are
efficient at exerting pressure in order to shape the global rules set by international
institutions like the WTO. They rally support from the governments of the countries in
which they operate, as these governments often “see their national interests linked to the
competitive position of the large firms that operate there” (Tansey 1). From the
government’s perspective, if a big pharmaceutical firm earns more profits from patents in
foreign countries, the GDP of the home country will increase and, in turn, the home
country will have a more competitive position on the world market.
The pharmaceutical industry endorses and justifies strong patent systems
internationally because “if copying is allowed in developing countries, these drugs will
be exported to developed country markets, where the industry makes most of its profits”
(Roffe, Spennemann and von Braun 12). If an original, brand-name drug is the only one
available to consumers, then consumers are left with no choice but to spend the money
and purchase that drug. When drugs are copied and produced as generic drugs, as
happens when a patent runs out or when a compulsory licence is issued, the generic drugs
can be sold at a cheaper price undermining the price of the original brand-name drug. To
employ standard economic theory, an increase in supply decreases demand and prices
Therefore, drugs copied in developing countries and exported to developed
countries at a reduced price are problematic for the pharmaceutical industry. The
presence of a generic drug undermines their ability to set prices, and further undermines
their profits. Not surprisingly, Big Pharma makes the greatest profits in developed
countries where the markets can usually bear substantially higher prices coinciding with
the ability of consumers to afford it – as opposed to the price being set in relation to the
The most popular argument put forth by Big Pharma to explain why the industry
puts so much pressure on keeping these patent systems strong is that its research and
development (R&D) would significantly suffer from the lack of funding that would result
without these protection systems. Lack of funding, in turn, impedes the development of
new drugs – new drugs which, according to Big Pharma, will benefit everyone in the end.
The validity of the argument that R&D would be disadvantaged by loosening the grip on
these patent systems can be scrutinized for a number of reasons: (1) considering how
much R&D really costs when compared to other expenses, such as the money directed
towards the marketing strategies of pharmaceutical companies; (2) there is a substantial
role played by public funding s in R&D, which is often unaccounted for; and (3) there is
no evidence that policies like compulsory licensing have in fact reduced investment in
R&D (Roffe, Spennemann and von Braun 15). Funding loss to R&D is also the basis for
the pharmaceutical industry’s arguments against the implementation of price controls.
In 2005, “a Tanzanian worker would have to earn 500 hours of wages to get a
course of first-line tuberculosis treatment, compared with the one hour of wages
necessary for a Swiss worker” (Gathii 347). Activists from prominent NGOs, like MSF
and Oxfam, argue for pharmaceutical companies to adopt a “systematic and transparent
tiered-pricing policy, where prices for all essential medicines are set according to
people’s ability to pay” (Oxfam press release, 2007-11-24). A tiered-pricing system, they
argue, would have a significant impact on increasing the level of access to medicines for
the world’s poor without severely cutting profits for the pharmaceutical companies. Yet,
Big Pharma views tiered-pricing with scepticism.
From Big Pharma’s viewpoint, this is price control, and price controls harm
shareholders, employees, suppliers, and the public because, again, less money goes
towards developing new drugs and treatments. As Richard A. Epstein writes:
The pharmaceutical business may feature patents that create monopoly,
but so long as these are not acquired by a wave of the hand, everyone will
cut back investment to reflect the low valuation that any system of price
controls, however convoluted and indirect, imposes on the system. It is a
mug’s game that cannot be won here any more than with price controls on
gasoline or rent controls on apartments (Epstein 81).
In any case, a key question must be raised: how much R&D funding is actually put
towards improving healthcare treatments for the world’s poor?
A great deal of R&D is conducted primarily to investigate illnesses and conditions
that affect people in industrialized countries; these results are of no significance to the
poor. This focus obviously disadvantages people in developing nations. “Between 1975
and 1999, 1393 new drugs were developed, of which only 13 were for tropical
diseases…90 per cent of investment into health-related R&D has focused on concerns
that only affect 10 per cent of the global population” (Roffe, Spennemann and von Braun
13). Diseases like malaria and tuberculosis, which continue to be serious health issues in
developing countries, are marginalized in the R&D agenda while issues like obesity (a
major condition for industrialized nations) dominate. James Orbinski (former president of
the International Council of MSF) states that no new drugs have been developed for the
treatment of tuberculosis since 1967 and 95 per cent of active tuberculosis cases occur in
developing countries – not a surprising correlation.
Of course, there have been various instances where Big Pharma’s philanthropy
has shone through – pharmaceutical companies have reduced drug prices in developing
countries, companies have offered substantial discounts on ARVs (antiretroviral drugs),
and there have even been instances when companies have provided drugs and health
infrastructure for free. However, many agree with Carsten Fink, that even though “such
actions are laudable, they are not systematic and depend on the good will of private firms.
Clearly, the scale of the health crisis in the developing world is too large to be solved by
private philanthropy alone” (Fink 187). The global public health crisis is not an issue that
can be handled based on various acts of ‘good will,’ it needs to be permanently present in
the agenda itself; it needs to be a priority.
Where is the “Progress” here? Where is the “Development”?
The logic of Big Pharma and industrialized nations largely reflects the rhetoric of the old
“modernist paradigm” of development initiated in the 1940s and 1950s – the ideology of
“modernization” and the traditional view of “progress.” This ideology presumed that
“only through material advancement could social, cultural, and political progress be
achieved. This view determined the belief that capital investment was the most important
ingredient in economic growth and development” (Escobar 39). Robert Goldberg, former
director of the Manhattan Institute’s Centre for Medical Progress, summarizes the logic
of this concept of development in one phrase: “wealth begets health.” Goldberg argues
that the main method of bettering healthcare is to make poorer countries wealthier:
“improving health in poor countries requires a combination of improved protection of
property rights… [including] protection of intellectual property rights” (Goldberg).
This viewpoint – that private wealth leads to the betterment of all – is inherent in
the neoliberal development initiatives put forth by prominent international institutions
like the World Bank and the International Monetary Fund. Their development programs
are set up so that developing nations will privatize public services such as healthcare and
education. The central aim is for these countries to ‘free’ their economies in order for the
market to rule. The vision behind the ‘self-regulated’ market is the ideal that the benefits
from the accumulation of private wealth will ‘trickle-down’ to everyone; but “the history
of increasing reliance on neo-liberal development strategies suggests that the expected
benefits do not materialize for most of the world’s poor” (Andreasson 16). This
awareness is spreading even within mainstream economics.
Jeffrey Sachs, a world-renowned economist, has focused his career on
collaborating with governments and NGOs alike on matters of economic development,
global poverty, the cancellation of debt for developing countries, environmental
sustainability, and global health concerns.2 A constant thread throughout Sachs’ career
has been his interest in examining the relationships between poverty, health, and
development. In 2001, he led a WHO commission of macroeconomists and public health
specialists in producing the influential report called Investing in Health for Economic Development. One of the simplest yet crucial findings of this report, which gets to the
heart of the correlation between development and global health issues, is that: “Poor
health causes poverty and poverty causes poor health” (Sachs 204).
Sachs elaborates on this concept in his book The End of Poverty: Economic Possibilities for Our Time when he discusses the “poverty traps” that many of the
extremely poor countries in the world are caught in such as climate stress, environmental
Even though life-saving solutions exist to increase their chances for
survival – whether in the form of new farming techniques, or essential
medicines, or bed nets that can limit the transmission of malaria – these
families and their governments simply lack the financial means to make
2 Jeffrey Sachs works at Columbia University where he is the Director of The Earth Institute, a Quetelet Professor of Sustainable Development, and a Professor of Health Policy and Management. He was the chairman of the World Health Organization (WHO) Commission on Macroeconomics and Health (CMH) from 2000 to 2001. Currently he holds the esteemed position of Special Advisor to the United Nations Secretary-General Ban Ki-moon, and from 2002 to 2006, he acted as the Director of the UN Millennium Project and was Special Advisor to the United Nations Secretary-General Kofi Annan on the Millennium Development Goals.
These poverty traps can severely inhibit any of the market reforms or good
governance strategies implemented to aid development.
Sachs discusses malaria as a prime example of a “poverty trap” in poor countries.
Although malaria is a treatable disease, “it still claims up to three million lives per year,
mostly young children, about 90 percent of whom live in Africa … Low cost treatments
exist, but they do not reach the poor” (Sachs 196). Not only is malaria devastating for the
individuals and families that suffer from it, but malaria can also devastate a country’s
macro-development. An outbreak of malaria can prevent the development of investment
projects like new tourist sites, mines, or farm regions (Sachs 197). Access to items such
as insecticide-treated bed-nets and anti-malarial medicines would significantly reduce the
number of people that die of malaria every year but, “malaria sets the perfect trap: it
impoverishes a country, making it too expensive to prevent and treat the disease. Thus
malaria continues and poverty deepens in a truly vicious cycle” (Sachs 199). The same
can be said about the painful impacts of AIDS. Sachs makes it clear that although aid
initiatives, trade policies, and good governance may all be working towards the same
objectives of “development” and “progress,” one strategy may defeat another if the actual
harsh realities of the poor are not taken into account. We can, in the name of development
and progress, ‘free’ the markets, impose the strongest intellectual property rights system
possible, and construct an ‘idyllic’ marketplace for global trade, but if the people are
dying from the rampant spread of treatable diseases, they will be unable to function
Setting Global Rules: The ‘Nitty-Gritty’ of the WTO TRIPS Agreement
The large number of specific obligations defined in the legal framework of TRIPS
marked a significant shift from past WTO agreements. The TRIPS Agreement was also
far more “controversial because it seemed to favour the interests of exporters (mostly
industrialized countries) more than the interests of importers (most developing nations)”
(Gallagher 93). Although many developing countries expressed resistance to putting
intellectual property rights into WTO agreements, they felt there was no choice since they
wanted continued market access to developed countries in other areas of trade, such as
What’s more, the TRIPS Agreement did not merely outline ‘suggested’
international norms that nation-states should follow in regards to intellectual property
rights. It implemented an enforceable regime under the Dispute Settlement
Understanding (DSU) through which “[O]nce the existence of a violation has been
determined, the affected country can apply cross-retaliations to the non-complying
country, in any area covered by the World Trade Organization (WTO) Agreement”
through sanctions (Correa 2). Thus, with the TRIPS Agreement, WTO Member-states
lost much of the power they possessed prior to TRIPS when they were able to consider
the welfare of their own particular national interests and use their own discretion in
determining which matters they wanted to cover under intellectual property rights laws.
In fact, a study published by the United Nations in 1975 shows that many countries,
developing and developed alike, did not allow the patentability of pharmaceutical
products. This ensured a lower cost of access for the country’s population, and/or allowed
the government to protect the national pharmaceutical sector from competition with more
advanced sectors in other countries (Roffe, Spennemann and von Braun 13).
There are, however, “flexibilities” within the TRIPS Agreement that provide
Member-states with some power over how they exercise patents in their own countries.
Members have the freedom to “define the broad parameters of a patentable invention,”
and can implement measures to sidetrack a patent owner’s monopoly of a patent in
specific situations as outlined in the Agreement. One such measure that allows for this
kind of flexibility is the research exception. Countries will implement this exception so
that researchers can use a patented invention to understand it better for the purposes of
TRIPS also includes the “Bolar” or “regulatory” provision which is employed
when governments want to allow generic drug manufacturers to use a patented product
before the patent has expired so that they can get marketing approval from the necessary
public health authorities. This provision enables generic manufacturers to release their
generic version of the drug on the market as soon as the patent licence expires. A patent
owner’s monopoly over a patented product or process might also be superseded in cases
where the owner is partaking in anti-competitive practices; meaning that the intellectual
property right is being used in a way that inhibits competition and obstructs trade or
technology transfer. TRIPS also allows for the use of parallel importation, which means
that companies can import the cheapest-priced drug from another country where a patent
exists. This can effectively drive down the prices of pharmaceuticals (Roffe, Spennemann
The one flexibility measure in TRIPS that runs into the most controversy with Big
Pharma is compulsory licensing. A compulsory license enables a third party to use a
patent without the patent owner’s authorization. A government can use this compulsory
licence to give one of its own agencies or a private company the right to produce drugs
under a generic label. Royalties are paid to the patent owner on each sale but these will be
minimal in order to keep the drug price as low as possible. Big Pharma’s main problem
with these flexibility measures is that they undermine its monopoly power and price-
setting ability – to use compulsory licensing as an example, it can successfully “lower the
price of medicines as much as 95%,” severely cutting into profits (Wallach and Woodall
95). It is not surprising then that certain conditions were attached to the flexibilities
outlined in TRIPS to ensure that their usage would be minimal.
Under the TRIPS Agreement, compulsory licensing could only be enacted under
certain stipulations. Consideration for a compulsory licence was on an individual basis,
and negotiations were required between the party wanting the licence and the patent
holder to ensure at least an attempt to agree on a voluntary licence prior to the issuance of
a compulsory one. TRIPS did state that negotiations would not be required if the country
were in a state of “national emergency,” or if the government needed to correct anti-
competitive practices. Once a compulsory licence was issued, it could only be applied
within the parameters set when it was authorized; and the licence could only be used for
the domestic market (Roffe, Spennemann and von Braun 15-16). These flexibilities made
TRIPS “unlike many other WTO agreements, [because] within the TRIPS Agreement
there [was] space to manoeuvre. However, as with all WTO issues, the ability to access
this flexibility [came] down to issues of power” (Wallach and Woodall 95).
Despite such provisions, there was justified fear in how TRIPS would affect the
welfare of the weaker publics of developing nations – the bottom billion. “Intellectual
property rules create monopolies for medicines sold by multinational pharmaceutical
companies, keeping inexpensive, generic medicines, which can reduce the cost of
medicine in a sustainable way, off the market” (Oxfam Briefing Paper). In Egypt, the
increase in the price of drugs after TRIPS was estimated to be five to six times the price
of non-patented products (Correa 35). One economist from the traditionally ‘neoliberal-
conservative’ World Bank even estimated that “the minimum welfare loss to a sample of
developing countries (Argentina, Brazil, India, Mexico, Korea and Taiwan) would
amount to a minimum of US$3.5 billion and a maximum of US$10.8 billion, while the
income gains by foreign patent owners would be between US$2.1 billion and US$14.4
billion” (Correa 35). The interests privileged by the inclusion of pharmaceuticals in the
TRIPS Agreement seem to be quite clear – they are those of Big Pharma and the
developed countries in which these multinational pharmaceutical companies are based.
TRIPS as “Organized Irresponsibility”
The actions and overall ideology of Big Pharma as legislated through the TRIPS
Agreement perfectly reflects what Ulrich Beck has labelled proof of the “industrial
fatalism” and “organized irresponsibility” which govern the practices of modern-day
global capitalism. Beck asks, “What good is a legal framework that prosecutes
technically manageable small risks, but legalizes large-scale hazards on the strength of its
authority, foisting them on everyone, including even those multitudes that resist them”
(Beck 69)? Beck raised this question about global ecological concerns; however, it is
easy to apply the question to global health issues and the legislation of TRIPS. Looking
beyond all of the flexibilities, stipulations, and other legal technicalities in the TRIPS
Agreement, the issue of intellectual property rights and the accessibility of medicines is
quite literally a matter of people’s health or illness, of increased standards of living or
poverty – of life or death. While Big Pharma argues for maintaining high levels of R&D
funding to save the lives of future generations, in the interim millions of lives are lost
because of a lack of access to medicines.
The previous points may sound dramatic and radical, as if uttered by a person
solely appealing to emotions as the basis for argument. However, how ‘radical’ are these
statements? Are we really “imprisoned by our dependence on [the] rationality” of the
industrial fatalism which Beck cautioned us about (Beck 58)? Perhaps we can be so
‘rational’ in following the organized standards of ‘red tape,’ that we are incapable of
seeing beyond it; and therefore, incapable of deconstructing issues with a simpler
rationality and responsibility – which would be saving lives versus not saving lives.
Is there a remedy to this dangerous industrial fatalist illness? The actions on the
ground of subaltern counterpublics and their demand for more accountability from Big
Pharma demonstrate how this illness is being successfully combated. In his book, The Bottom Billion: Why the Poorest Countries Are Failing and What Can Be Done About It,
Paul Collier remarks that the WTO’s trade policies, structured essentially as a
marketplace, neglect the needs of the “bottom billion” and thus, help perpetuate their
The WTO trade policy is determined by national trade representatives who
see their role as negotiating a deal. Within this framework there is no
scope for using trade policy as an instrument for development. For trade
policy to become an instrument of development, ministries of trade have
to be ordered to change their priorities from extracting the best bargain to
fostering development in the bottom billion. But ordered by whom?
The people who are currently ordering the change in priorities that Collier
discusses have risen out of their ‘communities of fate’ and joined together in
‘communities of choice’ to form subaltern counterpublics which fight against the
demands of Big Pharma. The TRIPS Agreement may have established the strong publics’
dominant discourse in the WTO’s legislation; but it is evident that the efforts and
successes of subaltern counterpublics have created a forceful counter-discourse as seen in
the South African Government’s Medicine Act (1997) controversy, Brazil’s ongoing
fight to maintain a good level of accessibility for its citizens, the ‘Battle of Seattle’
(1999), and the Doha Declaration (2001).
South Africa: The Protests of AIDS Activists’ are Heard
“One in five adult South Africans, one in seven Kenyans, and one in three Zimbabweans
has HIV/AIDS,” which is why some liken HIV/AIDS to the plague that devastated
Europe in the 14th century (Wallach and Woodall 94). In response, the South African
government implemented the Medicines and Related Substances Control Amendment
Act (1997) in order to help its citizens gain better and more affordable access to anti-
AIDS drugs and other essential medicines. The Act:
encourage[d] the use of generic drugs, prohibit[ed] pharmaceutical
companies from paying doctors bounties for prescribing their products …
and institute[d] parallel importing as a means to control pharmaceutical
costs. The Medicine Act also allow[ed] the government to require
compulsory licensing. Under Article 31 of the TRIPS Agreement, such
compulsory licensing [was] legal if royalties [were] paid to the patent
Although both compulsory licensing and parallel importing are provisions
supported by the TRIPS agreement, the U.S. government claimed that South Africa was
infringing on international patent rights because of the wording of the new legislation.
The disputed portion of legislation, Section 15C, was “designed to override the
exhaustion of rights problem by giving the Minister of Health new over-riding
administrative discretion” (ClearyandRoss 450). The United States feared that a “broad
interpretation of 15C would allow the government to bypass the Patents Act and issue
‘fast track’ compulsory licenses on pharmaceutical patents” (ClearyandRoss 453).
U.S. Secretary of Commerce Richard Daley took up the matter with his
South African counterpart. This led to a revision of South Africa’s
proposed legislation, addressing some of the U.S. industry’s concerns. The
U.S. still was not satisfied, and engaged in a ‘full court press’ in late 1997
to persuade South Africa to suspend the law entirely (Wallach and
Consequently, the U.S. Office of the Trade Representative (USTR) labelled South Africa
as a “Special 301 ‘watch list’ country – a status that could lead to trade sanctions” (Roffe,
The Pharmaceutical Manufacturers’ Association of South Africa (PMA) would
also use WTO obligations as their basis for challenging the Act. In February 1998, “39
international [pharmaceutical] firms, including the South African Pharmaceutical
Manufacturers Association (PMA) brought legal action against Nelson Mandela and the
South African Department of Health” (Roffe, Spennemann and von Braun 16-17). The
PMA withdrew its case against the South African government in late 1998 due to
international public pressure, only to bring the same lawsuit back again in January 2001
(von Soest and Weinel 215). The PMA’s representatives claimed that it was the “arbitrary
power” of the Minister of Health that was at issue, but the allowance of compulsory
licensing was more at the core of the problem – that is, the money that would be lost from
these patents was the real issue at hand.
Subaltern counterpublics raised a massive and unified global outcry to counteract
the legal action brought against the South African government by the United States and
the pharmaceutical companies. “Intellectual property rights activists tended to demonize
the large pharmaceutical companies as a core part of their political strategy, and linkage
of this campaign to the southern African HIV/AIDS epidemic clearly enhanced popular
interest in the case” (ClearyandRoss 453). This enabled these cases to attain a
significant amount of exposure in the popular media. NGOs and other movements
introduced “counter-concepts” into the public consciousness like “no patents on life” and
“patents kill.” Developing nations later adopted these concepts when formulating their
proposals to the WTO and the World Intellectual Property Organization (WIPO)
(Dutfield 538). Leading NGOs, like MSF, employed and continue to employ “counter-
experts” in the battle against Big Pharma, using academic consultants with legal
experience and hiring staff to concentrate solely on intellectual property rights issues
Campaigns were organized in South Africa by the Treatment Action Campaign
(TAC), the country’s main advocacy group for increased levels of access to anti-
retroviral drugs. In the United States, American AIDS activists organized mass
demonstrations, particularly against the Al Gore presidential campaign, which had a
significant impact (Clearyand Ross 453-454). While Gore formally announced that he
was running for president, AIDS activists were chanting “Gore’s Greed Kills” and “after
two of Gore’s next three speeches were similarly disrupted, the White House began
reaching out to activists, indicating that it was looking at changing its position” (Wallach
and Woodall 96). The U.S. government dropped the trade pressures it had issued against
South Africa, and Vice Presidents Al Gore and Thabo Mbeki came to a resolution in
1999. “During the November-December WTO Ministerial in Seattle, the Clinton
administration announced it would offer special treatment for health-related intellectual
property disputes, taking into account health issues as well as commercial concerns”
(Wallach and Woodall 96). AIDS activists successfully shifted U.S. policy and secured
an interpretation of TRIPS that would support similar actions taken by governments of
The United States government had changed its position; however, the PMA did
not drop the lawsuit. Demonstrations took place in front of the headquarters of several
major pharmaceutical companies in Europe and North America (von Soest and Weinel
215-216). In the spring of 2001, “300,000 people from more than 130 countries signed an
international petition launched by MSF calling on the companies to drop the case” (MSF
press release), and there was continued international public pressure and negative media
attention for the PMA. “Interestingly, the government, HIV/AIDS activists, scientists,
and other previously divided stakeholders joined hands to win the court case against the
TNPCs [transnational pharmaceutical companies], although they followed different
agendas” (von Soest and Weinel 216). These diverse publics emerged from their
‘communities of fate’ to find kinship and the power to enact social change for an
important ‘community of choice.’ Because of this communal activism, the 39
pharmaceutical firms finally dropped their lawsuit on April 18, 2001.
There was a definite moment of crisis in the WTO over discourse and how
different parties were interpreting the conditions and uses of the TRIPS Agreement. The
strong publics put forward one discourse, while the subaltern counterpublics proposed an
alternative. As a result, the lawsuits brought against the South African government were
diverted, and the Medicines and Related Substances Control Amendment Act (1997)
remained largely unaltered. The only “concession” made by the government was to
reaffirm that it would adhere to the stipulations of TRIPS (von Soest and Weinel 216).
Similar success occurred in the case of Brazil where subaltern counterpublics again held
Brazil’s Crusade Against Big Pharma
The government of Brazil has a history of balancing international trade laws and national
social policies for the benefit of its people. Therefore, when Brazil, as a Member-state of
the WTO, had to shape its laws to suit the TRIPS agreement in 1994, it obliged, but with
certain conditions attached to safeguard the welfare of its citizens. The Industrial
Properties Law signed on May 14, 1996 by President Fernando Henrique Cardoso
provided a high level of protection for pharmaceutical patents, yet the legislation was
written in a way to allow for a liberal interpretation of TRIPS obligations.
Over the years, Brazil has developed a strong pharmaceutical manufacturing base
composed of many private and public manufacturers. Because of this local industry, the
prices of drugs are lower than they would be if Brazil had to import the same drugs.
Brazil’s manufacturing capacity also provides the government with a powerful weapon
against the pharmaceutical industry since it can use the threat of compulsory licensing to
negotiate with Big Pharma. In 1997, the Brazilian government was able to include anti-
retroviral therapy in its universal access to healthcare policy which “guarantee[d] the
entire population prevention and treatment for HIV/AIDS, the right to diagnosis, and the
right for universal and free access to all resources to treat the disease” (Wallach and
Woodall 99). As part of this program, the government provides seventeen anti-retroviral
drugs to its citizens free of charge – eight are generic drugs produced in Brazil and nine
are brand-name drugs imported from other countries (Cohen I-17). These healthcare
policies led to “a sharp decline in AIDS morbidity, mortality, opportunistic infection
rates, and hospitalizations” (Cohen, I-17).
In June 2000, the U.S. government brought legal action against Brazil through the
DSU system arguing that the Brazilian government violated the TRIPS Agreement
through its legislation permitting “local manufacturers to produce products [when] a
patent holder does not produce them locally.” This legislation allowed for the
authorization of compulsory licences and parallel imports in circumstances where some
of the production for the required pharmaceuticals was based in another country (Wallach
and Woodall 98). The U.S. government claimed that Brazil was violating the TRIPS
condition that all manufacturing under a compulsory licence must be done only in and for
the domestic country’s market (Roffe, Spennemann and von Braun 17). The U.S. was
concerned that Brazil’s production of cheap generic versions of anti-retroviral drugs
weakened the U.S. pharmaceutical industry.3 Due tointernational pressure from activist
groups, the “USTR [United States Trade Representative] announced a consultative
mechanism to promote cooperation with Brazil on HIV/AIDS issues in June 2001,” and
in the end, the U.S. government dropped its complaint against Brazil (Wallach and
The Brazilian government further exemplified success in improving accessibility
to medicines with actions just prior to the Doha Conference of 2001. Brazil’s Minister of
Health, Jose Serra, threatened to issue the first compulsory licence for an HIV/AIDS drug
after negotiations failed between the Brazilian government and the pharmaceutical
company, Hoffmann-La Roche Inc. Serra argued the Hoffman-La Roche had, in effect,
left the country in a state of emergency because the price of pharmaceuticals were so
3 Ironically or not, “in 2001, [when] faced with a mere handful of cases of anthrax, the US government threatened to override Bayer’s patent on ciprofloxacin by endorsing compulsory licensing” (The Lancet). The U.S. government demonstrated blatant hypocrisy since it habitually discourages other countries from using compulsory licensing but threatened to use this measure when their own citizens’ health was at risk.
high. Brazil could easily have followed through on the threat to issue a compulsory
licence, since they had the manufacturing capacity to do so, but instead, the Brazilian
government used the threat of compulsory licensing to bargain with Hoffmann-La Roche
Inc. so that in the end the company reduced the price of the anti-retroviral drug Nelfinavir
by 40% (Cohen I-17). Brazil’s lessons for other developing countries observing the
negotiations were telling and clear. Despite pressures from Big Pharma, the United
States, and the TRIPS intellectual property rights regime, social activism and the
governments of developing nations had the power to put saving people’s lives first on the
The Battle at Seattle: An “Icon of Dissent”
Cases like the Brazilian and South African fight against Big Pharma and the U.S. raised
awareness as to how WTO legislation, multinational corporations, and some
industrialized nations utilized the discourse of globalization to construct a neoliberal
economic agenda solely for the benefit of the stronger publics. For many members of the
weaker publics and subaltern counterpublics, globalization came to signify a dystopian
direction for the world, a direction that would only serve to marginalize further the
world’s poor and further destroy the environment.
In response, the subaltern counterpublics mobilized together to create a powerful
counterdiscourse known as the ‘anti-globalization movement.’ Although anti-
globalization protesters have worked against neoliberal globalization, they are not
opposed to using the communicative tools that globalization advanced, such as the
Internet. The anti-globalizers’ use of this tool demonstrates how “the continuous
movement of people and information feeds a cycle of dissent with far-reaching
consequences” and as a result, “paroxysms of public demonstration have intensified in an
age of globalization” (Drache, Clifton and Froese). This intensification was evident as the
anti-globalization movement’s cycle of dissent came to a climax with the Seattle protests
Throughout 1999, … people got plenty of chances to join the anti-WTO
campaign. A main rallying point was the StopWTORound distribution list
… [which] enabled many to receive detailed information on different
aspects of the WTO. The communication was facilitated even more by
various sites on the Internet, the umbrella website of the anti-WTO
coalition being the most famous … While groups with local ties
concentrated on mobilization and direct action, more transnational-based
groups provided information and frames to feed the action (Van Aelst and
This networking led up to November 30, 1999 and the massive street protest
demonstration in front of the Seattle Center where the WTO’s Ministerial Conference
The tens of thousands of protesters and members of NGOs present voiced their
concerns regarding the environment, labour issues, consumer protection, and most
particularly, free trade. The protesters wanted to take a stand against unfair trade
arrangements (such as the inclusion of pharmaceuticals in the TRIPS Agreement) which
continued to privilege the interests of industrialized nations and multinational
corporations while simultaneously ignoring the needs of developing nations. This
monumental event, etched into the collective memory as the ‘Battle of Seattle,’ was and
still is the anti-globalization movement’s signature “icon of dissent.”
These controversial cases involving developing countries and the anti-WTO
protests did not go unnoticed. The next WTO ministerial meeting on November 14, 2001,
in Doha, Qatar, took into account the claims made against Big Pharma; as a result the
discourse around WTO legislation regarding intellectual property rights and access to
medicines shifted. The subaltern counterpublics had made themselves heard and the
dominant discourse shifted because of it.
A Reframed Agenda: The Doha Declaration
The Doha Ministerial Conference was a pivotal event in the WTO’s history for a few
different reasons. It was the “first comprehensive negotiating mandate in the global
trading system since 1986, it incorporated the most NGO involvement to date, and,
finally, the needs and concerns of developing countries seemed to be placed at the
forefront of the agenda (Gallagher 100).
In the months leading up to the Conference, it was clear that the WTO wanted to
forge better relations with NGOs to avoid another ‘Battle of Seattle.’
The WTO organized presentations by selected NGOs to Members in
Geneva, held briefings and workshops with NGOs, established a public
discussions forum (still in place) on its website for organized and self-
initiated discussion, circulated NGO views and papers to Members and
published a monthly bulletin on NGO/WTO contacts and events of interest
By encouraging open communication, the WTO not only tried to ensure that NGOs were
aware of WTO activities, the organization also attempted to remain informed of any
NGO concerns that should be addressed in the preparation process to the upcoming
Conference to avoid potential conflicts.
These communication efforts continued throughout the Conference itself. The 365
NGOs present were provided with “office and workshop facilities for conferences
including press conferences in an NGO centre adjacent to the main conference centre.” In
addition to this, NGOs “were briefed daily by senior WTO officials and by some
ministers on the progress of the discussions” (Gallagher 105). With the creation of a
better information-loop between NGOs and the WTO, the actors of global civil society
were given more agency in the legislative process. They were provided with greater
knowledge and more forums through which to voice their opinions – leading to more
In the weeks leading up to the Doha Round, conflicts of interest arose over the
interpretation of certain elements of TRIPS. Brazil, Thailand, and African countries
among others “sought legally binding language stating that the TRIPS Agreement ‘shall’
be interpreted and implemented to allow compulsory licensing and other public health
measures” (Wallach and Woodall 100). These countries wanted to make it clear that
countries without the manufacturing capacity to produce drugs under compulsory licence
should be able to import the necessary drugs from a country with the capacity to do so.
Therefore, the developing nations came together to draft a proposal for their desired
interpretations (Option One), and in it, they asked that the language allow for as much
flexibility as possible. On the other side of the debate, developed countries such as the
U.S. and Switzerland drafted their own proposal (Option Two). They demanded that the
parameters for the use of compulsory licensing be as narrow and restrictive as possible.
For example, they wanted to block any country from importing medicines produced
under compulsory licences, and they wanted to specify that a compulsory license should
only be issued in cases of extreme emergencies and only for HIV/AIDS pandemics
(Wallach and Woodall 100). Ultimately the discussions that took place at the Conference
resulted in the WTO’s adoption of the Doha Declaration on TRIPS and Public Health.
In light of previous legal cases, like those brought against South Africa and
Brazil, the Doha Declaration stressed the importance of:
Implement[ing] and interpret[ing] the TRIPS Agreement in a way that
supports public health – by promoting access to existing medicines and the
creation of new medicines – and that the TRIPS Agreement does not and
should not prevent Member governments from acting to protect public
Moreover, the Declaration specifically emphasized that circumstances of national
emergency should be left to the discretion of each WTO Member-state. In relation to this,
the Declaration explicitly talked about how tuberculosis, HIV/AIDS, and malaria would
be deemed reasonable grounds for declaring a national emergency. Overall, the general
impression was that each Member-state should feel free to use the flexibilities of TRIPS
to the fullest extent when deemed necessary – including using compulsory licensing and
being “free to establish their own regimes on parallel imports or ‘exhaustion of
intellectual property rights’(Doha Declaration 2001, paragraph 5(d))” (Roffe,
The Doha Declaration also acknowledged unresolved issues that had not been
covered in the TRIPS Agreement, which would need to be addressed in the future. One of
the main outstanding issues was that some developing countries lacked the manufacturing
capacity to produce their own drugs, therefore in a state of emergency, another country
would have to be issued a compulsory licence to produce the necessary drugs for the
country in need. Although TRIPS allowed for compulsory licensing, one of the major
conditions for its use was that the drugs produced under compulsory licence remain
within the domestic market, thus exports under these licences would be prohibited
(Gallagher 89). After all the negotiations at the Doha Round, there was no resolution
around what the legal boundaries would be for countries unable to produce drugs locally
nor what the rights would be in terms of importing compulsory licensed drugs from other
In the absence of a resolution, the Declaration appropriately assigned two tasks to
the TRIPS Council. The first was “to find a solution to the problems countries may face
in making use of compulsory licensing if they have too little or no pharmaceutical
manufacturing capacity”;4 and the second, “to extend, the deadline for least-developed
countries [LDCs] to apply provisions on pharmaceutical patents until 1 January 2016”5
The Doha Conference was an official turning point for the weak publics and
subaltern counterpublics. Not only did they express their needs but also, through
legislation, they showed how to protect and advance their interests, ensuring for the
4 An original deadline for this task was set for December 31, 2002 but a solution was not actually agreed upon until the Geneva WTO Round on August 30, 2003. 5 The original deadline for LDCs to change their patent systems to coincide with the TRIPS agreement was January 1st 2006.
future that attention must be given to them. Following the Doha Declaration, Oxfam and
MSF fought for the expansion of Article 30 in the TRIPS Agreement so that generic drug
manufacturers could acquire compulsory licences that would permit them to produce
drugs solely for exportation to other countries lacking the capacity to produce the drugs
themselves (Loff, MSF press release, 23.11.2002, www.msf.org).
Once again, the calls for expansion were answered by the WTO and the spirit of
Doha maintained its momentum. At the WTO General Council meeting in Geneva on
August 30, 2003, the Council agreed upon the “Waiver Decision” which waives all
restrictions prohibiting the exportation of drugs under compulsory licensing on the
condition that the exporting member manufactures only enough drugs to meet the
emergency conditions of the importing member. Other conditions actualized in this
meeting included permitting LCDs to use the flexibilities of the TRIPS Agreement in
regional arrangements so they could take advantage of economies of scale. It was also
conceded that Members would no longer be required to get advance authorization for
compulsory licence but would only have to “notify their intentions to use the export or
import side of the waiver” (Gallagher 113). At this WTO Council meeting, Director-
General Supachai Panitchpakdi optimistically stated that, “The final piece of the jigsaw
has fallen into place, allowing poorer countries to make full use of the flexibilities in the
WTO’s intellectual property rules in order to deal with the diseases that ravage their
people” (Gallagher 112). The Doha Declaration and subsequent addendums were
significant moves towards placing human interests above the market principles of Big
Pharma; however, by no means was the fight over.
The Current Tribulations of TRIPS
For developed countries, the main obligations of TRIPS were mandated to be applied at
the beginning of 1996. The deadline for LDCs to conform to the stipulations within the
TRIPS Agreement was initially set for January 1, 2006, however, with the Doha
Declaration on TRIPS and Public Health, this deadline for pharmaceutical patents was
extended to January 1, 2016.6 The deadline for developing countries and some transition
economies to implement patents and data protection of pharmaceuticals in agreement
with the TRIPS regulation was January 1, 2000. However, some developing countries
had that deadline extended to January 1, 2005 due to a special provision in Article 65.4 of
the Agreement. This provision stated that if a developing country did not have a patent
protecting a product or technology at the time when TRIPS was officially implemented
(in 1995) then that country would have 10 years to do so.
For the transition periods when developing countries7 and least-developed
countries8 would legislate the implementation of the TRIPS patent rules for
pharmaceuticals, the WTO mandated the “mailbox patent system.” Under this system,
those wishing to obtain a patent for a pharmaceutical product would put in an application,
to be filed and stored. The application will be examined once the transition period is
In March 2005, India amended its 1970 Indian Patents Act in accordance with the
2005 deadline to comply with the TRIPS obligations for pharmaceutical patents. The
Indian government made a decisive effort to keep in mind human interests when it chose
6 A WTO decision on November 30, 2005 extended the deadline in all other areas of the TRIPS Agreement for LDCs to July 1 2015. 7 The transition period for developing countries would be from 1995 to 2000 or 2005 (per Article 65.4). 8 The transition period for LDCs would be from 1995 to 2016.
to allow any generic drug manufacturer that had made a “significant investment” and that
was already producing and marketing drugs to continue to do so. The new Act also
granted permission to any generic manufacturer that put in an application under a
mailbox patent and that ended up getting approval from the Indian government (MSF
Article April 21 2005). This was a significant stand since India produces vital medicines
to developing nations for keeping diseases and epidemics at bay. In fact, “more than half
the medicines now being used for AIDS treatment in developing countries come from
India” (Oxfam Press Release February 15, 2007).9 Another significant amendment was
that the “export of medicines produced under compulsory license [would] be possible
based on the sole notification by the importing country . [and] India [would] no longer
[require] that a compulsory license be granted in the importing country” (MSF Article
April 21 2005). Resistance erupted from pharmaceutical giants like Novartis, Merck and
Pfizer which all protested against India’s production and exportation of essential generic
The crux of the controversy between the Indian government and Big Pharma is
India’s use of safeguards that were decided upon in the WTO’s “Waiver Decision”
regarding the exporting and importing of essential medicines through the implementation
of compulsory licensing. Countries that granted compulsory licenses on AIDS drugs in
2004 include Malaysia, Mozambique, Zambia, and Zimbabwe. The compulsory licences
permitted generic manufacturers in India and Africa to produce AIDS drugs without
buying the patent rights to do so. These countries have used the provisions of the WTO’s
legislation with public health as the top priority, thereby saving millions of lives in the
9 “India is the world’s biggest producer and exporter of generic medicines to developing countries, particularly in Africa, reaching millions of people.” For instance, “90% of anti-retrovirals used in Zimbabwe’s national treatment program come from India” (Oxfam Press Release February 15, 2007).
process. In a statement prepared for Oxfam in 2006, John le Carré, author of The
Big Pharma” is dishonouring hard-won international agreements designed
to allow lifesaving generic drugs to be produced and marketed in countries
where there is urgent and demonstrable need … With unlimited legal
resources Novartis is challenging India’s sovereign right under
international law to supply cheap, non-patented drugs in situations where
the public health is at risk. If the case succeeds, Novartis will have
protected the health of its account books at the expense of those who will
die because they can’t afford the drugs that could save them (Oxfam Press
‘TRIPS-plus’ conditions and U.S. Free Trade Agreements
“With developing countries becoming more assertive at the WTO, governments in
developed countries have responded by actively encouraging developing countries to sign
up to bilateral and regional free trade agreements and investment agreements providing
so-called ‘TRIPS plus’ IPR [intellectual property rights] standards in exchange for
improved market access” (Dutfield 535). The ‘TRIPS-plus’ protection aims at preventing
developing nations from using the safeguards already set in the Agreement to the fullest
extent possible. These ‘TRIPS-plus’ conditions include: “extending patents and copyright
to new kinds of subject matter; eliminating or narrowing permitted exceptions including
those still provided in U.S. and European IPR laws; extending protection terms;
introducing new TRIPS-mandated IPR rules earlier than the transition periods allowed by
TRIPS; and ratifying new WIPO [World Intellectual Property Organization] treaties
containing TRIPS-plus measures” (Dutfield 535). The United States has successfully
negotiated TRIPS-plus conditions into free trade and bilateral agreements with countries
such as: Vietnam (2001), Jordan (2001), Singapore (2003), Chile (2003), Australia
(2004), Morocco (2004) and DR-CAFTA (Dominican Republic, Costa Rica, El Salvador,
Guatemala, Honduras, Nicaragua) (2005) (Fink and Reichenmiller 285).
In bilateral agreements with Australia, Jordan, Singapore, and Vietnam, for
example, the United States has legislated conditions that “limit the use of compulsory
licensing to emergency situations, antitrust remedies [anti-competitive practices], and
cases of public noncommercial use [government use]” (Fink and Reichenmiller 286). In
the Doha Declaration though, it was clear that WTO Members could implement
compulsory licences when necessary for the health of their citizens. The United States
further uses the arrangements in these bilateral agreements to discourage the use of
compulsory licensing by requiring an “exclusivity of test data.” This means that:
no competing manufacturer may rely on those data for a period of five
years to support a request for approval for its own drug. The compilation
of new test data by competing manufacturers may take several years and
be prohibitively expensive. For that reason, test-data exclusivity may pose
a second obstacle for governments to make effective use of compulsory
Again, the TRIPS Agreements only specified that test data could not be used for “unfair
commercial use” (Fink and Reichenmiller 287).
In considering all of these efforts to perpetuate a strong IPR system over
pharmaceuticals, there is a wonderful irony when one takes into account the flood of
MNCs that are moving their scientific and technical operations to countries like China
and India. Since patents will increasingly be awarded to inventors in these developing
countries, developed nations like the United States may change their perspective on
‘TRIPS-plus’ conditions and their overall position on IPRs (Dutfield 545).
When the United States experiences marked increases in the proportion of
domestic patents being granted to inventors from advanced developing
countries like China and India, something which currently seems
inevitable, the tide may well turn back to the patent skepticism of
yesteryear, especially if in consequence the reliably massive annual trade
surplus in royalties and licence fees is converted into a regular deficit
Once the governments of developed countries like the United States look at patents a
little differently, they might not align themselves with Big Pharma as closely as they once
did. The U.S. government and other developed nations might change their lobbying
tactics and actually join in advocating for better access to the very medicines, which they
recently tried to block at every opportunity.
“This is OURS”
Big Pharma and its supporters have attempted to appropriate lifesaving knowledge from
the Commons for the sake of capital accumulation, and their intention is clear. They are
saying: “This is mine.” Fortunately though, there are many unwilling to concede to that.
So long as developed nations (primarily the U.S. government) and multinational
pharmaceutical companies (like Novartis, Merck and Pfizer) continue to demand ‘TRIPS-
plus’ protection; so long as Big Pharma fails to implement a tiered-pricing policy set
according to what people can pay; and so long as R&D funding continues to neglect
research into diseases that severely impact poor people in developing countries, NGOs
and developing nations will continue the fight to hold Big Pharma to account (Oxfam
Press Release November27,2007). The fight for access to medicines is by no means over,
and therefore, it is important to engage in perspectives and research areas that will further
develop and elucidate the questions and issues discussed in this report.
I. Public and Private Partnerships
One area of interest worth investigating further is the many private and public
partnerships that have developed from collaborations between the pharmaceutical
industry, NGOs, and governments. An early example of such a partnership occurred in
1965 when Wyeth, one of the world’s largest pharmaceutical companies, obtained a
patent for its development of the bifurcated needle, which greatly improved the
effectiveness of vaccination techniques. Wyeth decided to give the patent to the World
Health Organization to assist in smallpox vaccinations forgoing any of the profits from its
A more recent example is the efforts of the William J. Clinton Foundation to
negotiate deals with pharmaceutical companies in order to lower the prices of anti-
retroviral treatments by thirty to fifty percent. In 2003, The Foundation was able to
broker a deal with three Indian pharmaceutical companies (Cipia, Ranbaxy and Matrix)
as well as a South African company (Aspen) so that HIV-infected people in thirteen
countries in Sub-Saharan Africa and the Caribbean could get “anti-retroviral drug
cocktails for as little as thirty-eight cents per person a day or less than half the price of the
most affordable drugs . available in some of the target countries” (The Economist).
These kinds of partnerships have been beneficial to vaccine production, new drug
development, and health delivery programs in developing countries (Foege 390). Writing
about the strengths of these partnerships, William H. Foege expresses a desire for this
private/public cooperation to branch out even further. One way he suggests might be for
corporations to encourage their managers to donate time and expertise to working in the
healthcare programs of developing countries. Foege believes this would not only benefit
the developing countries but the corporations as well:
If promising managers were expected to spend a year or two working on
the improvement of health delivery systems in developing areas,
supervising field workers, and developing health training programs, the
training component for global health could be strengthened and
corporations would have executives with a new understanding of the
The rise of these partnerships opens new opportunities for global health
governance to recognize how the boundaries between the private and public sectors are
being manipulated to provide access to medicines. For the same reason, there are aspects
of Big Pharma’s philanthropic involvement that should remain open to scrutiny. For one
thing, Big Pharma’s continued emphasis on philanthropic donations to improve access to
medicines in developing countries does not amount to the monumental good that would
come from larger structural changes within the pharmaceutical industry itself, such as the
implementation of tiered pricing systems. In any case, it is beneficial to research existing
private/public collaborations in order to foresee new possibilities for future initiatives as
II. Generic Drugs: A Global Powerhouse
A second key research area is the emerging power of the generic drugs industry. The
generic industry has a crucial role to play in threatening and combating Big Pharma’s
monopoly on patents and the production of pharmaceuticals. To understand the profound
impact the generic industry has, we return to India’s pharmaceutical industry. India is
known as the “pharmacy of the developing world” because “more than two-thirds of
generic medicines exported from India are sold in developing countries at a fraction of
the cost of patented brand medicines” (Oxfam, News and Publications, Aug. 6, 2007).
Millions of individuals obtain medicines that they would otherwise not be able to
afford under brand-name labels and NGOs have better purchasing power to buy
medicines for the healthcare programs that they run because India produces these
inexpensive generic medicines. Sandhya Venkateswaran, head of advocacy for CARE
International, a humanitarian organization which aims to fight global poverty in India,
has said that: “CARE has been able to buy more than twice the amount of anti-retrovirals
to treat the HIV and AIDS patients we work with in Peru, thanks to the generic industry
in India” (Oxfam, News and Publications, Aug. 6, 2007).
Another example that demonstrates the impact of the generic drug industry is the
generic drug company, Apotex, the largest pharmaceutical company in Canada. Apotex
has been known to introduce drugs “at-risk” meaning that it introduces drugs on the
market before patent litigation has been settled. Apotex released its generic version of
GlaxoSmithKline’s anti-depressant, Paxil in 2003 (Saul). By introducing these drugs “at-
risk,” Apotex runs the risk of incurring huge costs if they lose the patent cases brought
against them. However, in taking that risk, Apotex partially destabilizes Big Pharma’s
monopoly and gets more affordable medicines out to the public faster. A thorough
analysis of the relationship and the tensions between the generic drug industry and Big
Pharma is crucial to improving our understanding of how the generic market could be
manipulated to provide better access to medicines.
III. “Big Pharma” and Global Activism
A third area of future research is the examination of campaigns and initiatives taken by
NGOs. This area of activity has been and will continue to be a dynamic catalyst in the
fight for access to medicines. Undertaking an in-depth account of the activities of
organizations such as Oxfam, MSF and Universities Allied for Essential Medicines,
would demonstrate how social activism has made Big Pharma and governments react.
From acting as watchdogs of the pharmaceutical industry to lobbying governments with
legislative proposals to taking to the streets in protest, the activism of these organizations
has proven repeatedly that civil society can take their fight for access to medicines to the
front lines and actually cause huge waves of change. Analyzing the different strategies
and resulting successes and failures of NGOs and social movements would provide
significant research, especially for those organizing future initiatives.
A paradoxical conundrum arises over the question of whether globalization has
marked the devolution of power into the hands of the people and away from higher
authoritative structures, or whether globalization has facilitated a concentration of power
at higher levels and thus, moved power increasingly out of people’s reach. It would seem
that power is in fact moving in both directions.
When looking at the ‘legitimized’ discursive arenas of the global public sphere,
such as the WTO, it is important to acknowledge that the dominant discourses and
agendas these arenas produce are often the work of a select few, privileged players who
get to write global rules for the rest of us. Because multinational corporations and
developed countries have accumulated more sway in these institutionalized spaces, they
have been able to exercise greater power in bending international laws and norms, and in
turn, they govern the economic integration and the communication flows of globalization
to suit their interests. However, just as these groups develop ways to harness the new
technologies and processes of globalization in their favour, so too do the groups who rise
up to challenge the “powers that be.”
The message to take from this is that it is possible. Agendas are set by the
dominant discourses of the “powers that be” such as Big Pharma, the United States
government, and/or the WTO, but it is possible to challenge those agendas and the rules.
What’s more, now more than ever before, it is possible to change those rules, and this
presents exciting opportunities for agency in the geopolitical landscape of power. There
is a multiplicity of publics in the global public sphere, and the stronger publics are
beginning to confront the fact that the subaltern power is a force to reckon with. The
counter-discourses constructed by subaltern counterpublics have ensured that the needs of
the marginalized weaker publics do not remain neglected. This report has revealed that
from the birth of TRIPS to its rebirth in the Doha Declaration on TRIPS and Public
Health, subaltern actions have infiltrated dominant agendas, effectively changing them.
When these subaltern counterpublics fight against an intellectual property rights
system that operates to inhibit medicines from reaching those in dire need of it, they are
reconceptualizing the laws that are supposed to balance private property and the needs of
the common good and fighting to reclaim lifesaving knowledge from the global
Commons. Stated in even more foundational principles, when fighting for access to
essential medicines, this subaltern power fights for the right to health and fundamentally,
the right to life. They are saying, “This is OURS and we have the right to claim it.” And,
their experience shows that it is possible to do so.
Appendix I: The TRIPS Agreement
The Trade-Related Aspects of Intellectual Property Rights (TRIPS) Agreement was
agreed upon on January 1, 1994 during the World Trade Organization’s (WTO) Uruguay
Round and took effect January 1, 1995. The Agreement provides an international
regulatory framework for intellectual property rights which all WTO members are
obliged to follow. It includes matters relating to: copyright, trademarks, geographical
indications, industrial designs, patents, layout designs of integrated circuits and trade
As explicitly stated on the WTO’s official website, TRIPS outlines:
“ how basic principles of the trading system and other international intellectual
property agreements should be applied”
“how to give adequate protection to intellectual property rights”
“how countries should enforce those rights adequately in their own territories” “how to settle disputes on intellectual property between members of the WTO”
“special transitional arrangements during the period when the new system is being
TRIPS Agreement and Controversy of Access to Medicines
The WTO’s decision to include pharmaceutical processes and products in the
international rules set by the TRIPS Agreement was and still remains a highly disputed
topic. Humanitarian organizations like Oxfam and MSF argue that having a rigid
international system that standardizes the implementation of pharmaceutical patents can
be detrimental to developing nations which should be able to structure their own systems
to allow for as much access to essential medicines as possible for their citizens. Big
Pharma enthusiasts, on the other hand, argue for a stronger protection of drug patents to
ensure that innovation is stimulated and to ensure that more funds can be put towards the
Appendix II: Glossary of Relevant TRIPS Terms
A patent owner’s monopoly of a patented product or process might be superseded in
cases where the owner is partaking in anti-competitive practices meaning that the
intellectual property right is being used in a way that inhibits competition and obstructs
“Bolar”or “Regulatory” Provision
This provision employed when governments want to allow generic drug manufacturers to
use a patented product before the patent has expired so that they can get marketing
approval from the necessary authorities. This enables generic manufacturers to release
their generic version of the drug on the market as soon as the patent licence expires.
A compulsory licence enables a third party to use a patent without getting permission
from the patent owner. A government can use this compulsory licence to give a
government agency or a private company the right to produce drugs under a generic
The term generic signifies when a patented product is copied by another manufacturer
and then is sold under the name of the chemical ingredient or under another brand-name
Under the “mailbox patent system”, those wishing to obtain a patent for a pharmaceutical
product must put in an application, which is then filed and stored and does not need to be
examined until after the transition period is completed. A pharmaceutical product under a
mailbox patent could be granted “exclusive marketing rights . for five years or until the
patent is granted or rejected, whichever is shorter” (Fink 190).
Parallel importation means that companies can import the cheapest-priced drug from
another country where a patent exists which can effectively drive down the prices of
pharmaceuticals. To better illustrate how parallel importation operates, here is an
example that the WTO uses on its official website:
“For example, suppose company A has a drug patented in the Republic of Belladonna and the Kingdom of Calamine, which it sells at a lower price in Calamine. If a second company buys the drug in Calamine and imports it into Belladonna at a price that is lower than company A’s price, that would be a parallel or grey import.”
A patent is the legal means through which a new invention (i.e. a drug) or new piece of
information (i.e. the chemical process to create a new drug) is prohibited from being
made, used, or sold by any party other than the patent owner. The TRIPS Agreement
ensures that patent owners have their product or process protected for 20 years from the
date the patent application is filed. There are, however, exceptions to the rights of patent
holders which are specified in the TRIPS Agreement. These exceptions include: the
research exception, the “Bolar” exception, cases of national emergency; the need to
correct anti-competitive practices; and non-commercial use (government use which
would include the use of compulsory licensing).
Countries will implement this exception so that researchers can use a patented invention
to understand it better for the purposes of advancing science and technology.
For more information on any of these concepts and terms, please follow this link to the
WTO’s official website where all of the sections of the TRIPS agreement are described in
Bibliography
Andreasson, Stefan. “Stand and Deliver: Private Property and the Politics of Global
Dispossession.” Political Studies, Vol. 54 (2006): 3-22.
Beck, Ulrich. “Chapter 3: Industrial Fatalism and Organized Irresponsibility” and
“Chapter 6: The ‘Poisoned Cake’: Capital and Labour in a Risk Society.” Ecological Politics in an Age of Risk. Polity Press: Cambridge, 1995.
Castells, Manuel. The Rise of the Network Society. Oxford: Blackwell Publishers, 1996.
Cleary,Susan andDon Ross. “The 1998-2001 legal struggle between the South African
government and the international pharmaceutical industry: A game-theoretic analysis.”
The Journal of Social, Political, and Economic Studies. 27. 4 (Winter 2002): 445, 50 pgs.
Cohen, Jillian Clare. “Expanding Drug Access in Brazil: Lessons for Latin America and
Canada.” Canadian Journal of Public Health. 97. 6 (Nov/Dec 2006): I15, 4 pgs.
Collier, Paul. The Bottom Billion: Why the Poorest Countries Are Failing and What Can Be Done About It. New York: Oxford University Press, 2007.
Correa, Carlos Maria. Intellectual Property Rights, the WTO and developing countries: the TRIPS Agreement and Policy Options for Developing Countries. London: Zed Books,
Drache, Daniel, David Clifton and Mark Froese. “The Iconography of Dissent and Global
Politics.” A Digital Report from the Counter-Publics Working Group. Robarts Centre for
Dutfield, Graham. “Turning knowledge into power: intellectual property and the world
trade system.” Australian Journal of International Affairs. 59.4 (December 2005): 533-
Epstein, Richard Allen. Overdose: how excessive government regulation stifles pharmaceutical innovation. New Haven: Yale University Press, 2006.
Escobar, Aturo. “Problematization of Poverty: The Tale of Three Worlds and
Development.” Encountering Development: The Making and Unmaking of the Third World. Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press, 1995.
Fink, Carsten. “Intellectual Property and Public Health: The WTO’s August 2003
Decision in Perspective.” In Richard Newfarmer (ed.). Trade, Doha and Development: A Window into the Issues. Washington, D.C: The International Bank for Reconstruction and
Fink, Carsten and Patrick Reichenmiller. “Tightening TRIPS: Intellectual Property
Provisions of U.S. Free Trade Agreements.” In Richard Newfarmer (ed.). Trade, Doha and Development: A Window into the Issues. Washington, D.C: The International Bank
for Reconstruction and Development/The World Bank, 2006.
Foege, William H. “Blurring the Lines: Public and Private Partnerships Addressing
Global Health.” In Michael A. Santoro and Thomas M. Gorrie (eds.). Ethics and the Pharmaceutical Industry. New York: Cambridge University Press, 2005.
Fraser, Nancy. “Rethinking the Public Sphere: A contribution to the critique of actually
existing democracy.” In Craig Calhoun (ed.). Habermas and the Public Sphere
Cambridge Massachusetts, MIT Press, 1992.
Gallagher, Peter. The first ten years of the WTO 1995-2005. Cambridge: Cambridge
Gathii, James Thuo. “Third World Perspectives on Global Pharmaceutical Access.”. In
Michael A. Santoro and Thomas M. Gorrie (eds). Ethics and the Pharmaceutical Industry
New York: Cambridge University Press, 2005.
Goldberg, Robert Ph.D. “Introduction.” Health For Humanity: How Patent Protection
Saves Lives. Manhattan Institute for Policy Research. (Event Transcript), December 9,
2002 http://www.manhattan-institute.org/html/cmp12-02.htm.
Habermas, Jurgen. “The Public Sphere: An Encyclopedia Article.” in Meenakshi Gigi
Durham and Douglas Kellner (eds). Media and Cultural Studies: Keyworks. Malden,
Hardin, Garrett. “The Tragedy of the Commons.” Science. (1968) 162: 1243-1248.
Hardt, Michael and Antonio Negri. Excerpt from Multitude: War and Democracy in the Age of Empire. New York: Penguin, 2004.
Loff, Bebe. “World Trade Organization wrestles with access to cheap drugs solution.”
MSF press release (first appeared in The Lancet). November 11, 2002:
http://www.msf.org/msfinternational/invoke.cfm?component=article&objectid=8F72C5B
C-A883-4FFA-9F0ECE2AEB984539&method=full_html
May, Christopher. “Unacceptable Costs: The Consequences of Making Knowledge
Property in a Global Society.” Global Society. 16.2 (2002).
MSF. “South Africa: Public opinion forces 'Big Pharma' to back down.” MSF Report.
http://www.msf.org/msfinternational/invoke.cfm?component=report&objectid=BA36A2
96-6D30-4537-97F60157AB82AC8A&method=full_html
MSF. “The future of generic drugs made in India.” MSF Article. April 21, 2005:
http://www.msf.org/msfinternational/invoke.cfm?component=article&objectid=63C0C1F
1-E018-0C72-093AB3D906C4C469&method=full_html
Oxfam. “Patents vs. Patients: Five years after the Doha Declaration.” Policy and
Analysis, Briefing Paper. November 2006.
[12] The side product related to 6 was also formed, but the optical purityof O-allyl-l-tyrosine (2) into proteins in E. coli. The alkenefunctional group of this unnatural amino acid should provide[13] M. Shimazaki, H. Haram, K. Suzuki, G.-i. Tsuchihashi, Tetrahedronnew chemical methods for the selective modification ofLett. 1987, 28, 5891; K. Suzuki, E. Katayama, G.-i. Tsuchihashi,[14] R
Triathlon Summary Lecture 3: Common nutrition deficiencies- Are you at risk? Calcium Calcium is a major dietary mineral in the body, and is imperative for good bone health and healthy teeth. In addition, the skeleton protects our vital organs. Stress fractures in the bones are a high risk for athletes and can result from a number of dietary factors, including eating dis